direct reciprocity

直接互惠
  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    直接互惠是在反复的社会互动中合作演变的机制。根据文献,如果与伴侣多次接触,个人自然会学会采取有条件的合作策略。相应的模式极大地促进了我们对合作的理解,然而,他们经常对个人如何记住和处理回报信息做出强有力的假设。例如,当通过社会学习更新策略时,人们通常认为个人比较他们的平均收益。这将要求他们计算(或记住)他们对人口中其他所有人的收益。要了解更现实的约束如何影响直接互惠,当个人根据最近的经验学习时,我们考虑条件行为的演变。即使在最极端的情况下,他们只考虑了他们最后的互动,我们发现合作仍然可以发展。然而,这些人采取不太慷慨的策略,他们合作的频率比传统的平均收益低。有趣的是,一旦个人记住了最近两三次互动的回报,合作率迅速接近经典极限。这些发现有助于文献探索互惠合作需要哪种认知能力。虽然我们的结果表明,一些基本形式的回报记忆是必要的,记住一些互动就足够了。
    Direct reciprocity is a mechanism for the evolution of cooperation in repeated social interactions. According to the literature, individuals naturally learn to adopt conditionally cooperative strategies if they have multiple encounters with their partner. Corresponding models have greatly facilitated our understanding of cooperation, yet they often make strong assumptions on how individuals remember and process payoff information. For example, when strategies are updated through social learning, it is commonly assumed that individuals compare their average payoffs. This would require them to compute (or remember) their payoffs against everyone else in the population. To understand how more realistic constraints influence direct reciprocity, we consider the evolution of conditional behaviours when individuals learn based on more recent experiences. Even in the most extreme case that they only take into account their very last interaction, we find that cooperation can still evolve. However, such individuals adopt less generous strategies, and they cooperate less often than in the classical setup with average payoffs. Interestingly, once individuals remember the payoffs of two or three recent interactions, cooperation rates quickly approach the classical limit. These findings contribute to a literature that explores which kind of cognitive capabilities are required for reciprocal cooperation. While our results suggest that some rudimentary form of payoff memory is necessary, it suffices to remember a few interactions.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Pubmed)

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    直接互惠是社会困境中合作的有力机制。互惠的逻辑,然而,似乎要求个体是对称的,每个人都有相同的手段来影响彼此的收益。然而在许多应用中,个人是不对称的。在这里,我们研究了线性公益博弈中不对称的影响。个人可能在他们的禀赋(他们为公共利益做出贡献的能力)和他们的生产力(他们的贡献有多有效)方面有所不同。鉴于个人的生产力,我们询问哪种捐赠基金的分配最适合合作。为此,我们考虑两个最优性概念。第一个概念侧重于合作的弹性。各自的捐赠分配确保即使在最不利的条件下,充分合作也是可行的。第二个概念侧重于效率。相应的禀赋分配使群体福利最大化。使用分析方法,我们充分描述了这两种捐赠分配。该分析表明,两种最优性概念都有利于某些禀赋不平等:更有生产力的参与者应该获得更高的禀赋。然而,这两个概念在捐赠应该是多么不平等的问题上存在分歧。对复原力的关注会减少不平等。通过额外的模拟,我们表明,最优的禀赋分配需要同时考虑合作的弹性和效率。
    Direct reciprocity is a powerful mechanism for cooperation in social dilemmas. The very logic of reciprocity, however, seems to require that individuals are symmetric, and that everyone has the same means to influence each others\' payoffs. Yet in many applications, individuals are asymmetric. Herein, we study the effect of asymmetry in linear public good games. Individuals may differ in their endowments (their ability to contribute to a public good) and in their productivities (how effective their contributions are). Given the individuals\' productivities, we ask which allocation of endowments is optimal for cooperation. To this end, we consider two notions of optimality. The first notion focuses on the resilience of cooperation. The respective endowment distribution ensures that full cooperation is feasible even under the most adverse conditions. The second notion focuses on efficiency. The corresponding endowment distribution maximizes group welfare. Using analytical methods, we fully characterize these two endowment distributions. This analysis reveals that both optimality notions favor some endowment inequality: More productive players ought to get higher endowments. Yet the two notions disagree on how unequal endowments are supposed to be. A focus on resilience results in less inequality. With additional simulations, we show that the optimal endowment allocation needs to account for both the resilience and the efficiency of cooperation.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Pubmed)

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    许多进化过程发生在连续的表型空间中。因此,探索选择如何在连续空间中运行是有意义的。一种方法是自适应动力学,它假设突变体是本地的。在这里,我们研究了一个不同的过程,也允许非本地突变体。我们假设常住人口受到入侵者的挑战,入侵者使用从所有策略空间的随机分布中选择的策略。我们研究了直接互惠的重复捐赠博弈。我们考虑由两个概率给出的被动策略,分别表示合作者合作或叛逃后合作的概率。策略空间是单位广场。我们推导了进化动力学的平稳分布和平均合作率作为成本效益比的函数的解析公式。对于积极的反应策略,我们证明,如果合作区域的面积大于相当于利益的1/2,合作比叛逃更丰富,B,除以成本,C,超过[公式:见正文]。我们引入了以概率一稳定的策略的概念。我们还研究了一个扩展的过程并讨论了其他游戏。
    Many evolutionary processes occur in phenotype spaces which are continuous. It is therefore of interest to explore how selection operates in continuous spaces. One approach is adaptive dynamics, which assumes that mutants are local. Here we study a different process which also allows non-local mutants. We assume that a resident population is challenged by an invader who uses a strategy chosen from a random distribution on the space of all strategies. We study the repeated donation game of direct reciprocity. We consider reactive strategies given by two probabilities, denoting respectively the probability to cooperate after the co-player has cooperated or defected. The strategy space is the unit square. We derive analytic formulae for the stationary distribution of evolutionary dynamics and for the average cooperation rate as function of the cost-to-benefit ratio. For positive reactive strategies, we prove that cooperation is more abundant than defection if the area of the cooperative region is greater than 1/2 which is equivalent to benefit, b, divided by cost, c, exceeding [Formula: see text]. We introduce the concept of strategies that are stable with probability one. We also study an extended process and discuss other games.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Pubmed)

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    野生型挪威大鼠在复制良好的实验性食物提供任务中获得了回报帮助,但是评估接受帮助的价值的标准尚不清楚。我们测试了在决定返回帮助时获得的帮助的质量或数量是否更重要,以及合作伙伴的熟悉程度和自己的当前需求是否会影响此评估。我们通过实验改变了帮助者的饥饿状态,和熟悉或不熟悉的合作伙伴提供热量较高的食物(增加数量;胡萝卜)或食物中蛋白质和脂肪(提高质量;奶酪)。接受帮助的接受是我们评估大鼠价值的标准。熟悉程度,食物类型和饥饿状态相互作用并影响大鼠返回的帮助。与不熟悉的伴侣相比,老鼠对熟悉的伴侣的帮助较少。与不熟悉的合作伙伴,与捐赠较不喜欢的食物(胡萝卜)的伴侣相比,老鼠向捐赠了更多的伴侣(奶酪)提供了更多的帮助,如果他们吃饱了并收到了奶酪,他们会早点返回帮助。与熟悉的合作伙伴,接受奶酪的食物匮乏的老鼠比接受胡萝卜的饱足的老鼠得到了更多的帮助。我们的结果表明,挪威大鼠根据其质量评估接受帮助的价值,他们目前的需求和合作伙伴的熟悉,在往复得到帮助之前。
    Wild-type Norway rats reciprocate help received in a well-replicated experimental food-giving task, but the criteria to appraise the received help\'s value are unclear. We tested whether quality or quantity of received help is more important when deciding to return help, and whether partner familiarity and own current need affect this evaluation. We experimentally varied recipients of help\'s hunger state, and familiar or unfamiliar partners provided either higher caloric food (enhanced quantity; carrots) or food higher in protein and fat (enhanced quality; cheese). Reciprocation of received help was our criterion for the rats\' value assessment. Familiarity, food type and hunger state interacted and affected help returned by rats. Rats returned less help to familiar partners than to unfamiliar partners. With unfamiliar partners, rats returned more help to partners that had donated preferred food (cheese) than to partners that had donated less preferred food (carrots), and they returned help earlier if they were satiated and had received cheese. With familiar partners, food-deprived rats that had received cheese returned more help than satiated rats that had received carrots. Our results suggest that Norway rats assess the received help\'s value based on its quality, their current need and partner familiarity before reciprocating received help.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Pubmed)

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    直接互惠是基于同一个体之间重复互动的合作进化的强大机制。但是,只有当收益成本比超过取决于内存长度的特定阈值时,高水平的合作才会发展。对于一轮记忆的最佳探索案例,这个门槛是两个。这里,我们报告说,中间突变率导致高水平的合作,即使效益成本比仅略高于1,即使个人只使用最少的过去信息。这一令人惊讶的观察是由两种效应引起的。首先,突变会产生多样性,从而破坏叛逃者的进化稳定性。第二,突变导致了不同的合作者社区,这些社区比同质的社区更具弹性。这一发现是相关的,因为许多现实世界的合作机会具有较小的效益成本比,介于一到二之间,我们描述了直接互惠如何在这样的环境中实现合作。我们的结果可以解释为表明多样性,而不是一致性,促进合作的发展。
    Direct reciprocity is a powerful mechanism for the evolution of cooperation based on repeated interactions between the same individuals. But high levels of cooperation evolve only if the benefit-to-cost ratio exceeds a certain threshold that depends on memory length. For the best-explored case of one-round memory, that threshold is two. Here, we report that intermediate mutation rates lead to high levels of cooperation, even if the benefit-to-cost ratio is only marginally above one, and even if individuals only use a minimum of past information. This surprising observation is caused by two effects. First, mutation generates diversity which undermines the evolutionary stability of defectors. Second, mutation leads to diverse communities of cooperators that are more resilient than homogeneous ones. This finding is relevant because many real-world opportunities for cooperation have small benefit-to-cost ratios, which are between one and two, and we describe how direct reciprocity can attain cooperation in such settings. Our result can be interpreted as showing that diversity, rather than uniformity, promotes evolution of cooperation.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Pubmed)

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    直接互惠需要识别和记住社会伙伴的能力,记住他们以前的行为。“认知能力不足”被认为可能会削弱直接互惠合作的能力。在这里,我们比较了大鼠使用直接互惠的倾向及其在非社会任务中记忆和识别感觉线索的能力。雌性大鼠富含三种感觉方式之一(视觉,嗅觉或听觉)在学习任务中表现更好,当他们用丰富的特定感觉方式进行测试时。对于合作测试,在随后的三个互惠实验中,老鼠可以提供两个以前对食物的帮助不同的伴侣。在涉及嗅觉线索的非社会学习任务中表现更好的个人在一个实验中更成功地应用了直接互惠。然而,在实验中防止视觉提示和身体接触,大鼠应用直接互惠规则,而与嗅觉提示在学习任务中的表现无关。这表明嗅觉识别能力增强,尽管是有益的,不是老鼠通过直接互惠合作的能力的先决条件。这可能表明,当老鼠拥有有关其社交伙伴的所有类型的信息时,个人在确定提供多少帮助时,可以应用互惠决策规则以外的其他标准,比如胁迫。有趣的是,当所有个体都被限制在主要依赖嗅觉记忆时,个人独立于他们在非社会环境中记忆嗅觉线索的能力而应用直接互惠。因此,当没有观察到直接互惠时,“认知能力不足”可能不是真正的原因。
    Direct reciprocity requires the ability to recognize and memorize social partners, and to remember their previous actions. \'Insufficient cognitive abilities\' have been assumed to potentially impair the ability to cooperate by direct reciprocity. Here we compare the propensity of rats to use direct reciprocity with their ability to memorize and recognize sensory cues in a non-social task. Female rats enriched in one of three sensory modalities (visual, olfactory or auditory) performed better in a learning task when they were tested with the specific sensory modality in which they have been enriched. For the cooperation test, during three subsequent reciprocity experiments the rats could provide two partners differing in their previous helpfulness with food. Individuals performing better in the non-social learning task that involved olfactory cues applied direct reciprocity more successfully in one experiment. However, in the experiment preventing visual cues and physical contact, rats applied direct reciprocity rules irrespective of their performance in the learning task with olfactory cues. This indicates that an enhanced olfactory recognition ability, despite being beneficial, is not a prerequisite for the rats\' ability to cooperate by direct reciprocity. This might suggest that when rats have all types of information about their social partner, individuals may apply other criteria than the reciprocity decision rule when determining how much help to provide, as for instance coercion. Interestingly, when all individuals are constrained to mostly rely on olfactory memory, individuals apply direct reciprocity independently of their ability to memorize olfactory cues in a non-social context. \'Insufficient cognitive abilities\' may thus not be the true reason when direct reciprocity is not observed.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

    求助全文

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    自从Press和Dyson在反复的囚犯困境中巧妙地发现ZD策略以来,一些研究已经证实了在反复的社会困境中存在零决定因素(ZD)策略。然而,较少研究多人ZD策略的进化性能,特别是从理论的角度来看。这里,我们使用状态聚类方法从理论上分析了两种代表性ZD策略的进化动力学:慷慨ZD策略和勒索ZD策略。我们考虑了多人ZD策略的两种新设置:具有所有ZD策略的比赛和具有所有记忆一策略的比赛,除了这些策略和一些经典策略之间的竞争。此外,我们调查了慷慨和勒索水平对慷慨和勒索ZD策略的进化动力学的影响,这在以前的研究中通常被忽略。理论结果表明,慷慨有限的玩家处于有利地位,勒索更严重的勒索者更容易站稳脚跟。我们的结果可能为更好地理解重复多人游戏中ZD策略的进化动态提供新的见解。
    Several studies have confirmed the existence of zero-determinant (ZD) strategies in repeated social dilemmas since Press and Dyson\'s ingenious discovery of ZD strategies in iterated prisoner\'s dilemmas. However, less research studies evolutionary performance of multiplayer ZD strategies, especially from a theoretical perspective. Here, we use a state-clustering method to theoretically analyze evolutionary dynamics of two representative ZD strategies: generous ZD strategies and extortionate ZD strategies. We consider two new settings for multiplayer ZD strategies: competitions with all ZD strategies and competitions with all memory-one strategies, apart from the competitions between these strategies and some classical ones. Moreover, we investigate the influence of the level of generosity and extortion on evolutionary dynamics of generous and extortionate ZD strategies, which was commonly ignored in previous studies. Theoretical results show that players with limited generosity are at an advantageous place and extortioners extorting more severely hold their ground more readily. Our results may provide new insights into better understanding evolutionary dynamics of ZD strategies in repeated multiplayer games.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

    求助全文

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    直接和间接互惠是促进群体内部和跨社会的亲社会行为的两个基本机制。这里,我们回顾了最近的工作,这些工作说明了(直接和间接)互惠框架如何阐明我们对亲社会行为相关的几个因素的理解-即群体成员,八卦,和第三方惩罚。Weproposethateachofthesefactorscanpromoteprosocieticbehaviorviaimpressivepsychologicalmechanismrelatedtodirectandindirecteutual:reputationalconcerns,期望,和对未来互动的预期。最后,我们讨论了采用这种框架的含义,并强调了未来研究的许多途径。
    Direct and indirect reciprocity are two fundamental mechanisms that promote prosocial behavior within groups and across societies. Here, we review recent work that illustrates how a (direct and indirect) reciprocity framework can illuminate our understanding of several factors related to prosocial behavior - namely group membership, gossip, and third-party punishment. We propose that each of these factors can promote prosocial behavior via proximate psychological mechanisms related to direct and indirect reciprocity: reputational concern, expectations, and anticipation of future interaction. Finally, we discuss the implications of adopting such a framework and highlight a number of avenues for future research.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Sci-hub)

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    Recent research suggests that children\'s sharing behavior is affected by experiencing or observing others\' sharing. These effects have been studied within research on the development of reciprocity and the effects of social modeling. In the current study, direct and indirect types of reciprocity and social modeling were assessed in 3- to 6-year-old children in three experiments (overall N = 382). In each experiment, we explored whether negative and positive social behavior were similarly paid back and forward in each of the different types of reciprocity. Moreover, we assessed the extent to which children reciprocated toward the protagonist who had performed the actual behavior and toward a neutral other. In Experiment 1, children experienced another\'s sharing behavior as recipients and could then allocate resources to this character and a neutral other. In Experiment 2, children observed another\'s sharing behavior and could then allocate resources to this character and a neutral other. In Experiment 3, children were asked to predict another protagonist\'s sharing in the same context as in Experiment 1. Overall, children treated the protagonist and the neutral other similarly and predicted others to do the same. Yet, they were more likely to reciprocate negative acts in indirect types of reciprocity. The results are interpreted with respect to the impact of observational learning and representational development on children\'s social behavior.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Sci-hub)

  • 文章类型: Journal Article
    Egg trading-whereby simultaneous hermaphrodites exchange each other\'s eggs for fertilization-constitutes one of the few rigorously documented and most widely cited examples of direct reciprocity among unrelated individuals. Yet how egg trading may initially invade a population of nontrading simultaneous hermaphrodites is still unresolved. Here, we address this question with an analytical model that considers mate encounter rates and costs of egg production in a population that may include traders (who provide eggs for fertilization only if their partners also have eggs to reciprocate), providers (who provide eggs regardless of whether their partners have eggs to reciprocate), and withholders (cheaters who mate only in the male role and just use their eggs to elicit egg release from traders). Our results indicate that a combination of intermediate mate encounter rates, sufficiently high costs of egg production, and a sufficiently high probability that traders detect withholders (in which case eggs are not provided) is conducive to the evolution of egg trading. Under these conditions, traders can invade-and resist invasion from-providers and withholders alike. The prediction that egg trading evolves only under these specific conditions is consistent with the rare occurrence of this mating system among simultaneous hermaphrodites.
    导出

    更多引用

    收藏

    翻译标题摘要

    我要上传

       PDF(Sci-hub)

公众号